Skip to main content
Advertisement
Browse Subject Areas
?

Click through the PLOS taxonomy to find articles in your field.

For more information about PLOS Subject Areas, click here.

  • Loading metrics

Ecosystem Services and Opportunity Costs Shift Spatial Priorities for Conserving Forest Biodiversity

Abstract

Inclusion of spatially explicit information on ecosystem services in conservation planning is a fairly new practice. This study analyses how the incorporation of ecosystem services as conservation features can affect conservation of forest biodiversity and how different opportunity cost constraints can change spatial priorities for conservation. We created spatially explicit cost-effective conservation scenarios for 59 forest biodiversity features and five ecosystem services in the county of Telemark (Norway) with the help of the heuristic optimisation planning software, Marxan with Zones. We combined a mix of conservation instruments where forestry is either completely (non-use zone) or partially restricted (partial use zone). Opportunity costs were measured in terms of foregone timber harvest, an important provisioning service in Telemark. Including a number of ecosystem services shifted priority conservation sites compared to a case where only biodiversity was considered, and increased the area of both the partial (+36.2%) and the non-use zone (+3.2%). Furthermore, opportunity costs increased (+6.6%), which suggests that ecosystem services may not be a side-benefit of biodiversity conservation in this area. Opportunity cost levels were systematically changed to analyse their effect on spatial conservation priorities. Conservation of biodiversity and ecosystem services trades off against timber harvest. Currently designated nature reserves and landscape protection areas achieve a very low proportion (9.1%) of the conservation targets we set in our scenario, which illustrates the high importance given to timber production at present. A trade-off curve indicated that large marginal increases in conservation target achievement are possible when the budget for conservation is increased. Forty percent of the maximum hypothetical opportunity costs would yield an average conservation target achievement of 79%.

Introduction

The ecosystem services (ES) concept comprises multiple contributions of ecosystems to human well-being [1], and has increasingly been used to raise awareness about the benefits that people derive from ecosystems [2], [3]. Considering ES when making decisions about the use of ecosystems could provide additional, anthropocentric arguments to support either management aimed at sustainable use of ecosystems or biodiversity conservation [4]. However, there is a still unresolved debate about to what extent components of biodiversity correspond with ES provision [4][7] and about the extent to which considering ES in decision making matches with biodiversity conservation objectives. Furthermore, accounting for ES within conservation planning is a fairly new practice [8][11]. In a conservation decision-making context, ES can be seen as benefits of conservation (many cultural and regulating services), or in the case of extractive provisioning services as an opportunity cost of conservation since their use may become restricted [8]. Trade-offs between extractive provisioning services, such as clear-cutting timber harvest, and other ES [12] and biodiversity protection [11], [13][15] require choices to be made on whether and where to protect an area. However, certain management systems restrict timber production and might thus allow for a synergy between an extractive provisioning service and other ecosystem services [16], [17] as well as some aspects of biodiversity conservation [17][21]. This leads to the crucial question within cost-effective conservation planning on how multiple-use areas, in which extractive exploitation is restricted, can potentially contribute to biodiversity conservation [22][24]. Cost-effective conservation means minimizing opportunity costs in terms of foregone commodity production [25]. As some conservation targets are compatible with a certain level of use [26], and since the opportunity costs of setting aside areas can be potentially high, a mixture of fully protected areas and areas allowing for partial use is likely to render more cost-effective and less conflictive conservation solutions, and may open opportunities for overall higher levels of biodiversity protection.

Spatial considerations play an integral role in the assessment of cost-effectiveness of conservation as the spatial configurations of important habitats [27] and of opportunity costs of conservation do not necessarily coincide [28]. A ‘policyscape’ may be defined as the spatial configuration of a mix of policy instruments [29], which aims at conserving biodiversity and ES at an aggregated spatial level. This framing suggests that there is an optimal and complementary spatial allocation of different types of instruments across a space containing all possible combinations of conservation values and opportunity costs within a study area. The spatial configuration of the policyscape has important practical implications for decision-making. For instance, it opens opportunities to evaluate disproportionate economic burdens between administrative units.

In this study, we suggest ways of creating cost-effective policyscapes. We address a mix of instruments that combines non-use (strict protection) and partial use (forestry restricted) for the conservation of forest biodiversity and ES in the county of Telemark (Norway). Indicators of the state of forests in Norway show a decline of certain species populations, especially of species associated to old-growth forest and species whose habitats are threatened by current forestry practices [14], [30]. There is a need to modify and adapt current conservation policies to help secure portions of unprotected biodiversity as well as to halt the processes that lead to forest biodiversity loss [14], [30], [31]. One approach is to increase protected forest areas in Norway, particularly within the ecological zones that are most favourable for forestry production [31]. Currently, new nature reserves in Norway are mostly implemented through voluntary forest conservation schemes that are based on a negotiation between forest owners and conservation authorities in Norway [32]. The exploration of different policyscapes for conservation of biodiversity and ES can give guidance to support such conservation efforts.

We used the conservation planning software Marxan with Zones [33] for near-optimal selection of areas for cost-effective policyscapes on a county level. Some experience has been developed in applying (earlier versions of) Marxan to conservation optimisation with ES [8], [11], [34][37]. However, to our knowledge integrated targeting of both biodiversity and multiple ES within a policyscape with different levels of protection has not been systematically studied before.

We addressed the following specific questions. We first analysed how optimal conservation outcomes differ between two scenarios that either take into account biodiversity only (scenario 1) or a set of ES next to biodiversity (scenario 2). The outcome of both scenarios was measured in terms of spatial configuration, area protected, conservation target achievement, and opportunity costs.

Second, we assessed the trade-off between biodiversity and ES conservation goals and timber production. We analysed this relationship by constructing a production possibility frontier (PPF) [25], while considering timber production as a private good and the sum of biodiversity features and other ES as public goods. These public goods are either spared from timber production in the case of full protection or jointly produced with the private good in the case of partial protection. We compared current instrument targeting, i.e. the effectiveness of current reserves to achieve conservation targets set in our scenario, to a ‘benchmark’ defined as the cost-effective policyscape traced by the PPF [38], [39].

Third, we explored differences in conservation burden across administrative units. For this purpose, we calculated the expected opportunity costs of an optimal conservation outcome for each municipality in Telemark. Significant differences in conservation burden across municipalities would suggest potential efficiency gains with concomitant distributional consequences, which could justify considering the introduction of a conservation instrument such as ecological fiscal transfer schemes [40].

Methods

Study area

Telemark is a county in southern Norway with an area of 15,300 km2 and a population of about 170,000 people [41], concentrated mainly in the south-eastern part of the county. The climate varies across the region with temperate conditions in the south-east (Skien, average temperature January −4.0°C, July 16.0°C, 855 mm annual precipitation) and alpine conditions in the north-west (Vinje, January −9.0°C, July 11.0°C, 1035 mm) [42]. The southern part of Telemark is mainly covered by forest exploited by forestry activities as well as by large inland lakes, with few towns and a small agricultural area (247 km2, i.e. about 1.6% of the land area) [41]. The northern part is characterised by treeless alpine highland plateaus covered by bogs, fens and heathlands [43]. The forest landscape in Telemark is characterized by coniferous and boreal deciduous forest [43]. Important forest ecosystem services include moose hunting, free range sheep grazing and timber production [44]. In addition, forests of Telemark sequester and store considerable amounts of carbon, prevent snow slides and provide opportunities for recreational hiking and residential amenities [44]. In 2011, conservation areas comprised about 5.1% in national parks, 4.6% in landscape protection areas (both types cover mainly highland plateaus), as well as 1.7% in nature reserves [41]. As a result of forestry activities, the status of biodiversity in forests of Telemark shows relatively low values compared to other ecosystems and regions within Norway [14]. We conducted our analysis for the forest area within Telemark, however, as forest field mapping is lacking for a small south-eastern part of the county [45], this area was excluded from the analysis.

Principle of Marxan with Zones

Marxan with Zones [33] builds on a heuristic optimisation algorithm that incorporates key principles of systematic conservation planning, including comprehensiveness, cost-effectiveness and compactness of the reserve system [46]. Marxan with Zones enables to consider zones with different levels of protection and thus spatial differences in costs, thereby allowing for planning and evaluation of policyscapes that include full and partial protection. Marxan with Zones requires a series of inputs, which are specified below.

Data input Marxan with Zones

ES and biodiversity features and conservation targets.

Depending on the scenario, a total of 59 (scenario 1, biodiversity) and 64 (scenario 2, biodiversity and ES) input features were used, respectively. Table 1 provides an overview of all features.

thumbnail
Table 1. Features, targets, fraction of targets to be achieved across the two zones (non-use and partial use), and contribution (effectiveness) of the partial zone in meeting respective targets.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0112557.t001

We included five key ES of importance within a Norwegian context for which spatial models have been developed (Table 1) [44]. We specifically included biodiversity features which are characteristic of old-growth, largely undisturbed forest and which are not maintained under current commercial forestry practices. We included 40 types of old-growth forest, to a large extent remnants of previously high-graded forests, occurring across a range of vegetation zones, climate zones and productivity conditions to represent the ecological variability across the county (Text S1 for details). Six proposed forest corridors of national importance that connect existing reserves [47] were included as a spatial indicator of conditions enabling species dispersal between habitats [48]. Forest habitats of particular conservation importance on a national level in Norway [49], [50] were also included. Three classes of priority habitats for conservation (very important, important and locally important) were taken from the Norwegian Environmental Agency’s database (Naturbase) [51]. In addition, we included ten types of important forest habitats (Table 1) from a Norwegian Forest and Landscape Institute database (MiS) [52].

Marxan with Zones requires setting quantitative conservation feature targets that reflect the proportion of the abundance of each feature to be protected. Targets were based on expert judgments and, wherever possible, on interpretation of policy documents (Table 1, and Text S1 for details). In order to verify targets an expert workshop was organised (Text S1). Written consent to participate in this study was obtained from the participants of the expert workshop.

The policyscape – definition of zones, zone targets, zone contributions.

Two types of area protection were included in our analysis, namely a non-use and a partial use zone. Non-use referred to nature reserves, where forestry is completely restricted, i.e. “use” refers to forestry activities. The partial use zone was an ‘umbrella’ zone covering three different current forms of protection where forestry is partially restricted, namely landscape protection areas, mountain forest (‘fjellskog’), and outdoor recreation areas (‘friluftsområder’) (Text S1). All current nature reserves in Telemark [51] were ‘locked-in’ as non-use zones and all current landscape protection areas were ‘locked-in’ as partial use zones, which means that spatial units overlapping with these areas were selected for the respective zone in each run of Marxan.

Marxan with Zones allows for distribution of the targets across zones. Zone targets were defined according to an own expert judgement about how well the non-use and partial use areas were compatible with the persistence of the respective feature. Zone targets (Table 1) were discussed, reviewed and as far as possible confirmed during the expert workshop (Text S1).

Marxan with Zones allows for differentiation of how effective zones are in order to achieve targets (zone contribution). We considered the effectiveness of partial use areas as “the relative contribution of actions to realizing conservation objectives” [53]. We assumed that non-use areas are fully effective to reach the targets of all features (100% contribution). There is growing, but yet inconclusive knowledge on how low impact logging could be compatible with biodiversity conservation [17][21], [54], [55]. This means that effectiveness of partial use areas is highly uncertain, and may affect features differently. Zone contributions were thus discussed and as far as possible confirmed during the expert workshop. In a sensitivity analysis we further explored the consequences of changing the zone contribution of the partial use zone (File S1).

Planning units.

The forest area in Telemark was divided into 43.513 grid planning units of 25 ha size (500 m×500 m). This resolution was suitable in terms of time and computing capacity, and considered relevant for land-use planning. Property sizes in Norwegian forests vary widely from as little as 0.1 ha to several hundred hectares [32] and as such are not a good guide to setting the size of the planning unit.

Opportunity costs of conservation.

Foregone timber harvest was selected as an indicator of opportunity costs of conservation since harvest activities are constrained by different forms of protection [25]. We used a net revenue (stumpage value) forest model to determine opportunity costs (Text S1). In non-use areas opportunity costs were set to 100%, while in partial-use areas, we estimated that restrictions would account for 25% of the stumpage value. This estimate was based on different logging restrictions [56] which ranged from 15% (landscape protection area), to 20% (outdoor recreation area) and 30% (mountain forest).

Analyses

Marxan with Zones was run 20 times with the parameters described above (for further parameter adjustments see Table S1 and Table S2). The software was run for both scenarios to determine the best solution and the selection frequency of each planning unit over all runs, which ranged from 0 (never chosen) to the maximum of 20 (chosen in each run) and indicated importance of a particular planning unit to achieve the overall conservation targets [57]. Marxan with Zones input files, including spatial information on all conservation features, can be found in the supporting information for scenario 1 (File S2) and scenario 2 (File S3).

Comparison of scenarios.

We used selection frequency of planning units to determine how the policyscapes of both scenarios differed spatially. Selection frequency of each planning unit to each of the two zones in scenario 1 (biodiversity only) was subtracted from selection frequency in scenario 2 (biodiversity and ES) to determine the difference. To compare the spatial configuration of the policyscapes, we calculated Pearson’s correlation coefficient between the selection frequency of each scenario for the partial and the non-use zone. We calculated Cohen’s Kappa on the selection frequency of each planning unit as a measure of agreement between the scenarios for each zone. To compare the two scenarios in absolute terms we calculated a number of statistics, including total costs, number of planning units without protection, planning units in the partial and non-use zone and average target achievement.

Trade-off between conservation target achievement and timber harvest.

The PPF was identified by running a series of cost constraints for scenario 2. Cost constraints are a restricting condition that defines an upper limit of costs when selecting planning units. We started by running the scenario with no cost constraints and close to 100% average target achievement, and recorded the total unconstrained cost. We then introduced cost constraints at different levels (80%, 60%, 40%, 20%, 10%, 5%, 1%) of the total unconstrained cost in consecutive runs (see Table S4 for parameter details). The value of timber production (horizontal axis in the PPF) was determined as the total sum of stumpage value across all planning units in the study area minus the opportunity cost of the best solution of each run. The vertical axis in the PPF was determined as the average percentage of target achievement for all biodiversity and ES features. To assess the opportunity costs of conservation and the conservation target achievement of the current existing reserve network, we used an overlay analysis (r.stats in GRASS GIS).

Conservation burden across Telemark.

To determine the conservation burden among the municipalities in Telemark, the expected opportunity cost for each municipality was calculated as the summed expected value of opportunity costs:(1)where Ce is the expected opportunity cost, fni is the selection frequency of non-use areas for planning unit i, fpi is the selection frequency of partial use areas for planning unit i and Ci is the opportunity cost of planning unit i. The denominator 20 stands for the number of runs in our case and the factor 0.25 specifies the harvest restriction in the partial use areas.

This analysis was run on scenario 2 with first, no cost constraint and, second, a medium cost constraint of 60% of the maximum costs needed to achieve close to 100% of the average targets. Opportunity costs per municipality were determined with zonal statistics in ArcMap for both expected opportunity cost layers and for current reserves. Municipalities were ranked according to relative opportunity costs, i.e. opportunity costs divided by municipal forest area. To analyse the spatial shift of the conservation burden across municipalities, Spearman’s rank correlation coefficient was calculated between the current situation and the unconstrained scenario, as well as between the 60% cost constraint and the unconstrained scenario.

Results

Incorporating ES in the policyscape for biodiversity conservation

Incorporating ES into the policyscape changed the absolute sum of area in the two zones, the opportunity costs (Table 2) as well as the spatial configuration of the policyscape (Figures 1 and 2). When considering ES, the sum of partial use areas increased by 36.2% and the sum of non-use-areas by 3.2% compared to the scenario that only considered biodiversity. Opportunity costs were 6.6% higher in scenario 2 than in scenario 1. As an illustration of a policyscape, Figure 1 shows the best solution per scenario for scenario 1 (a) and scenario 2 (b). Selection frequencies of planning units for both scenarios can be found in Figure S1. The differences in selection frequencies are shown in Figure 2 for the partial (a) and non-use zone (b). A positive difference means higher selection frequency in the policyscape of scenario 2 than in scenario 1, while a negative difference indicates a lower selection frequency in the policyscape of scenario 2 than in scenario 1. Comparison of the spatial configuration of the policyscapes of both scenarios led to the following results. Pearson’s correlation coefficient between selection frequencies of sites in the non-use zone was r = 0.90, while for the partial use zone, it was r = 0.58. This indicates that relatively larger differences can be expected in the partial use zone than in the non-use zone when ES were considered, which partly rests upon the fact that ES can, in contrast to most of the biodiversity features in this study, partly be protected in this zone. Cohen’s Kappa statistics was K = 0.577 (sig≤0.0001) for the non-use zone and K = 0.398 (sig ≤0.0001) for the partial use zone. These results imply ‘moderate agreement’ in non-use and 'fair agreement’ in partial use zone, respectively [58], which supports the observation of a relatively larger agreement between non-use areas in the different spatial configurations of the policyscapes.

thumbnail
Figure 1. Best solution of the reserve network for scenario 1 (a) and scenario 2 (b).

Scenario 1, considers biodiversity conservation criteria only; scenario 2, both biodiversity and ecosystem services criteria. Grey, areas available for forestry; blue, areas in the partial use zone and green, areas in the non-use zone. Current reserves are demarcated in dashed lines. Map inlay shows the location of Telemark within Norway (grey).

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0112557.g001

thumbnail
Figure 2. Differences in selection frequency of sites for partial (a) and non-use (b) areas.

The maps show the difference of scenario 2 (biodiversity and ES features) versus scenario 1 (biodiversity only). A positive difference means higher selection frequency in scenario 2 than in scenario 1.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0112557.g002

thumbnail
Table 2. Summary statistics describing the difference between scenario 1 (considering biodiversity conservation criteria only) and 2 (considering biodiversity and ecosystem services) in terms of opportunity costs, area in the different zones and average conservation target achievement.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0112557.t002

Trade-offs between conservation and timber production: Production possibility frontier (PPF)

The PPF shows a concave curve representing the trade-off between timber production and conservation of biodiversity and non-forestry related ES (Figure 3). Creating a reserve network to achieve the conservation targets comes at a cost of timber production. The marginal increase in conservation target achievement is initially high when the current constraint on conservation cost is relaxed (i.e. moving left in Figure 3). This marginal conservation gain decreases more rapidly after having passed a cost constraint of about 40% of the total cost required to achieve 100% of the overall conservation target. The current policyscape (black square) lies under the PPF curve, meaning that more cost-effective policyscape configurations than the current one are possible. This means that higher average target achievement could hypothetically be realised at current levels of timber production, or that the same target could be achieved at lower costs. At the same time, the location of the current policyscape shows a strong preference of decisions towards timber production. Consequently, the conservation targets we set in our scenario are barely met by the current reserve system (average achievement 9.1%).

thumbnail
Figure 3. Forest conservation-timber production possibility frontier (PPF).

Note that the x-axis (sum of timber production value) starts at 6.00 billion NOK. The maps indicate current reserve network (A) and selected (B–E) available, partial and non-use areas when current reserves are not locked-in. The spatially explicit solutions (policyscapes) are shown as maps on the trade-off between net revenues from timber production and average conservation target achievement, along a range of opportunity costs constraints.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0112557.g003

While Figure 3 shows the average target achievement of all 64 features, Figure 4 shows the development of target achievement along changing opportunity cost constraints for single, exemplary features (for all features see Table S3). Some features meet high targets at low (20%) cost constraints (carbon sequestration and one type of low productive old-growth forest), which means that these features did not constrain the solution to a high degree. Some conservation features decreased at higher rates than the average (e.g., one type of high productive forest and recently burned forest). Such features are more costly to be comprehensively conserved in a compact reserve network.

thumbnail
Figure 4. Forest conservation-timber production possibility frontier (PPF) for single, exemplary features.

Old-growth forest L, S, BN, TR = impediment and low productivity, spruce dominated, boreonemoral zone, oceanic-inland transition zone. Old-growth forest H, P, SMB, TR = high & very high productivity, pine dominated, South & Mid- boreal zone, oceanic-inland transition zone.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0112557.g004

Distribution of the conservation burden of cost-effective conservation areas

The creation of the policyscape for conservation of biodiversity and ES formed the basis for determining the ‘conservation burden’ across municipalities of Telemark (Table 3, spatial distribution in Figure S2). Conservation burdens across municipalities were slightly shifted in a (hypothetical) scenario with no cost constraint in which approximately 100% of the average target could be achieved compared to the current situation. For instance, while Porsgrunn ranked 6th in terms of the conservation burden of the current policyscape, it ranked 1st in the policyscape of with no cost constraints. The Spearman’s correlation coefficient between the current situation and the scenario with unconstrained costs was r = 0.67. The Spearman’s correlation coefficient between a 60% cost constraint and the unconstrained scenario was r = 0.46, which means that spatial priorities for conservation, and thus conservation burdens, shift with the level of the opportunity cost constraint.

thumbnail
Table 3. Absolute and relative conservation burden per municipality in the current situation, with a cost constraint of 60% and with no cost constraint.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0112557.t003

Discussion

A policyscape for conservation of biodiversity and ES

The use of spatial planning tools that simultaneously consider conservation of biodiversity and ES in a cost-effective way is a fairly new approach, facilitated by recent advancement in computational science. This approach provides a range of opportunities [8], [10], but still presents challenges in operationalization. Considering ES within biodiversity conservation could be beneficial for incorporating sustainable use of ecosystems [4] when achieving overall conservation goals in land use planning (land sharing), compared to a land use strategy that separates conservation and provision of ES (land sparing). A land sharing principle was included in our study in the partial use zone, which partly allows for the development of synergies between ES, biodiversity and timber production and which complements strict protection zones in policyscapes analysed in this study. In our analysis, we had to rely on expert-backed assumptions when describing the effects of the partial use zone on conservation. This is due to inconclusive knowledge on how restricted logging affects particular elements of biodiversity and ES [17][21], [55]. Our study suggests that in forest areas of Telemark the configuration of a policyscape for conservation changes when ES were incorporated (scenario 2) compared to considering only biodiversity conservation criteria (scenario 1). This change was twofold and included a change in total areas assigned to the two protection zones and a change in the spatial configuration of selected sites. Including ES resulted in an increase in the size of the reserve network, a result that is in line with previous studies [8], [36] in that when optimizing for cost-effective representation of conservation targets more areas with lower opportunity costs that contribute to target achievements of both biodiversity and ES are selected.

In contrast to former studies, we used different levels of protection, which enabled us to also specify the change in the policyscape in terms of the spatial distribution of the different zones. Including ES resulted in a strong increase in partial use areas (+36.2%), which was partly expected due to the fact that ES features were considered to be protected for a relatively larger proportion in partial use zones than biodiversity features (Table 1). The difference in spatial configurations of the policyscapes of the two scenarios can partly be explained by relatively low degrees of pairwise spatial overlaps between some ES and the biodiversity features (File S4). It also depends, for instance, on various combinations of biodiversity and ES features on cost-effective sites and proximity of suitable combinations to existing reserves. The difference in spatial configuration leads to different spatial prioritisations of sites to preserve in both zones and thus would have important implications for regional and local decision making.

Trade-off between commercial timber production and conservation of biodiversity and ES

Including ES next to biodiversity into a conservation scenario reflects different values [4], [59] and as such could lead to more informed policy decisions. In our conservation scenario we thus treated ES of public interest representing partly intangible values (regulating and cultural services) as conservation features with an own target. While in the ES discourse, ES are often treated as generally beneficial [4], here we shed light on potential specific trade-offs among ES and between ES and biodiversity conservation priorities. We included timber production in our analysis, a provisioning service that contributes to private economic benefits, and assessed the form of the trade-off curve (PPF) between timber production on the one hand and cultural and regulating services and biodiversity on the other. The existence of a trade-off on a system level was expected based on our assumption that outside the two conservation zones, elements of biodiversity and ES would not be conserved. This assumption might seem strong, but can be defended by the fact that the dominant form of forest management in Norway is characterised by large-scale clear-cutting [60].

From the PPF, we derive two broad policy conclusions. First, the currently designated nature reserves and landscape protection areas achieved a very low proportion (9.1%) of the conservation targets we set in our scenario. This is partly because the conservation network has not been initially designed to meet the conservation targets we defined in our study. For instance, while attention has been given to rare and threatened forest types [31], we did not assign different conservation targets to the different old-growth forest types, which might in practice be of different importance for forest biodiversity conservation. The result is, however, in agreement with the relatively little forest area that is currently allocated to conservation [31] due to low conservation budgets and conflicts. Further, our findings support the observation of a biased representation of protected areas towards high altitudes and lower opportunity cost areas [61]. This pattern, as well as the under-representation of productive forest in the current conservation network, have also been found for Norway [29], [31], [62]. Our present scenario was deliberately designed to include high productive forest, which partly explains the low target achievement of the current conservation network.

Second, the PPF analysis also provides insights for policy-makers regarding balancing private and public interests. It is a societal choice to determine the level of production of either timber or biodiversity and regulating and cultural ES. The PPF illustrates the high importance given to timber production at present. At the same time, it shows that the relationship between gains in conservation and opportunity costs is not linear. This means that high marginal improvements in conservation can be obtained with relatively smaller increases in costs when a low opportunity cost constraint is relaxed. Thus, with relatively little investment, e.g. spending 40% of the maximum opportunity costs, on average 79% of the scenario targets could be achieved under the assumptions applied in this study. However, inspection of the PPF curve also reveals that lowering the cost constraint reduces the probability of achieving conservation targets for certain habitats (e.g. recently burned forests, high productive forests) within the reserve network. In contrast, carbon sequestration reaches high proportions of the target at low cost which indicates that carbon sequestration can be seen as a co-benefit of protecting biodiversity and other ES, assessed at the scale of all prioritised full and partial protection areas across the study area. This is the inverse logic of the current international debate (i.e. REDD+), where carbon sequestration is targeted to be protected while (unmeasured) biodiversity is a (hoped for) co-benefit [63], but is in agreement with findings of process-based models in recent studies [17].

Uncertainties in creating the conservation scenario

We encountered several challenges in creating the conservation scenario. The choice of conservation features is a crucial factor that determines the outcome of the site prioritisation. Operationalizing biodiversity conservation requires quantifiable and obtainable indicators [64], [65]. Given restrictions on data availability, we believe that our choice of biodiversity surrogates represents a first step for planning the maintenance of biodiversity in Norwegian forest ecosystems.

Despite the “inevitable subjectivity” in setting conservation targets [66], there is some experience in setting targets for biodiversity conservation [65], [67]. However, setting explicit targets for ES when determining spatial priorities has seldom been done [68]. Current studies using Marxan for ES conservation have pointed out the need for experimentation, explicitly stated assumptions and expertise in setting targets given the absence of this information [8], [11], [36], [37], particularly because ES targets influence the size of the reserve network [35]. A systematic sensitivity test of target levels was, however, out of scope of this current study. ES targets may vary considerably because alternative means are available for substituting forest ES depending on location. Preferences for recreational hiking can shift outside the forest towards mountainous areas. In some areas, feasible technical substitutes for snow slide prevention by forests are available. Since different interests and values are reflected in ES, a systematic stakeholder involvement could provide more insight on target levels for each conservation feature. In a future study, sensitivity analyses could be run based on integrated consultation of forest owners. Because Marxan is a regional level policy-support tool its suitability to be used for conservation planning at the property level is restricted. For example, once priority areas have been identified in a regional planning exercise, local authorities in collaboration with the local forest association try to reach agreement with several adjacent property owners [32]. The conservation outcome is the result of multiple negotiations to achieve a single voluntary nature reserve, the final spatial configuration of which does not depend on the result of a near-optimal site prioritisation software. However, Marxan with Zones could be run iteratively on different agreement configurations to show how marginal conservation burden and target achievement are shifted to other locations, for instance when particular forest owners have declined to agree with an area which would in the first place have been prioritised. Scenario analyses in Marxan with Zones could help planners evaluate the cost-effectiveness of local level conservation decisions, in light of the portfolio of other options, instead of negotiating about one or a few sites at a time.

Another uncertainty in conservation planning lies in the underlying opportunity costs [69]. While we did not test this uncertainty in our analysis, we point out that the advent of forest harvesting for bioenergy could be a ‘game changer’ as it would probably change expected returns to forestry and thus change the spatial distribution of opportunity costs.

Partial use areas, where extractive resource exploitation is restricted, can host high levels of biodiversity [17], [18], [26], [55] and integrating such areas in conservation networks may improve overall conservation effectiveness by reducing costs and conflicts between different economic activities [53]. A combination of non-use and partial-use areas may also help to maintain a landscape that enables processes such as colonization and forest succession, particularly if non-use areas are small. The determination of effectiveness of zones to achieve a conservation target has been identified as a major challenge for conservation planning given limited availability of knowledge [34], [70]. For the sake of simplicity, we assumed a 100% effectiveness to protect biodiversity and ES for the non-use zone, given that this is the highest level of protection that can be achieved. We acknowledge, however, that considering a lower effectiveness level would most probably have led to a larger network of protected areas. In face of natural dynamics and disturbances, effectiveness of conservation areas should be monitored in terms of representativeness and persistence [66], [71]. Because of the uncertainty about the probability of biodiversity persistence in the partial use zone, we explored the consequences of changing the zone contribution for the partial use zone as input in Marxan for 46 biodiversity features (Figure A1 in File S1). With a lower zone contribution, Marxan with Zones tended to select more planning units in the non-use and less in the partial use zone despite considerably lower opportunity costs of the partial use zone; a result that is in line with the findings by Makino et al. [53] in a study of partial protection zones in a marine environment in Fiji.

Assessing regional level implications of site prioritisation for ES and biodiversity: conservation burden

Decision-making about cost-effective area allocation to protect biodiversity and ES takes place at various levels of governance that may justify the design of new policy instruments. Cost-effective selection of priority sites for conservation can guide measures directed to land owners, for instance by consultation with land owners of selected priority sites on whether they would agree to convert forestry land into voluntary nature reserves, as is the current practice in Norway [32]. While land owners voluntarily entering conservation agreements in Norway are generally compensated for their private opportunity cost [32] accumulated loss of forestry activity in a region may, on the one hand, result in unequal public conservation burdens, particularly across different municipalities. Large protected areas may lead to foregone business opportunities, loss of tax income and additional expenses for municipal governments. On the other hand, protected areas can also provide positive externalities to others, through tourism opportunities and protection of biodiversity more generally. Local governments can be compensated for costs of conservation by state-to-municipal “ecological fiscal transfers” [40], an instrument that has been implemented in Brazil and Portugal, and is currently being considered in several European countries [72]. Ecological fiscal transfers have mainly been based on compensation scaled by area. Proposals to scale ecological fiscal transfers using criteria reflecting the effectiveness of conservation in a municipality have generally been limited by the availability of spatially representative data on biodiversity. We have demonstrated how the creation of cost-effective policyscapes could be used to determine distributional effects of additional conservation efforts.

Conclusions

Marxan with Zones provides a spatially explicit way to include different types of ES and biodiversity conservation criteria to study a policyscape for cost-effective conservation. We have shown that, in the case of Telemark, including a number of ES shifts priority sites for conservation and increases the area of both a partial use and a non-use zone, compared to a situation where only biodiversity conservation criteria are considered. Conservation of a number of regulating and cultural ES leads to additional conservation efforts, in terms of higher opportunity costs and a larger area protected. We show how carbon sequestration can be viewed as a side-benefit of the protection of other ES and biodiversity in the context of the current Kyoto-based setting of national targets. This is opposite to current thinking about biodiversity as a hoped-for side-benefit of climate mitigation measures under REDD+. The current conservation situation in Telemark clearly prioritises timber production against the protection of biodiversity and ES, and relatively large marginal increases in conservation target achievement could be reached with modest additional investments in terms of compensation for foregone timber production. Our analysis also shows potential differences in conservation burden among municipalities in Telemark, opening the debate on policy instruments such as ecological fiscal transfers that support county-level cost-effective conservation through stimulation of local conservation efforts.

Although the integration of partial use areas into conservation could provide opportunities to increase cost-effectiveness in conservation, significant work is needed to document effectiveness of different levels of protection on particular conservation features. Despite the high level of uncertainty, a policy mix of conservation measures appears to have the potential to contribute to address the complexity of cost-effective conservation problems.

Conservation targets for many aspects of biodiversity and especially ES are currently absent. Conservation planning could be better operationalised with more knowledge on stakeholder preferences about the importance of ES as well as with more ecological knowledge on area size needed to preserve a biodiversity feature.

Our analysis should not be understood as a concrete regional management plan, but rather as an exploratory analysis to provide insights about the current forest conservation situation, about which conservation outcomes could be achieved at which opportunity costs levels. In practice, selection of protected areas is often based on other criteria and motives than cost-effective, comprehensive site prioritisation [61]. Decision makers could use the results of this study to encourage disproportional conservation efforts at local level that achieve cost-effective, near optimal solutions to a conservation problem of multiple biodiversity and ES features. For this to happen, decision makers have to decide to what extent additional information, such as mapping of ES, could be integrated into land-use planning [73]. We have shown how ES mapping, conservation benchmarking and distributional impact analysis using conservation planning tools could inform decision-making and support compensation of land owners’ and local governments’ conservation efforts.

Supporting Information

Figure S2.

Spatial distribution of the conservation burden.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0112557.s002

(DOC)

Table S1.

Parameter settings of Marxan with Zones.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0112557.s003

(DOC)

Table S2.

Parameters and results of the PPF analysis.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0112557.s004

(DOC)

Table S3.

Target achievement of conservation features.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0112557.s005

(DOC)

File S1.

Sensitivity analysis of the partial use zone contribution.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0112557.s006

(DOC)

File S2.

Marxan with Zones input files – scenario 1.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0112557.s007

(ZIP)

File S3.

Marxan with Zones input files – scenario 2.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0112557.s008

(ZIP)

File S4.

Pairwise spatial overlap of conservation features.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0112557.s009

(XLSX)

Acknowledgments

We thank Lars Hein and Lucie Vermeulen for useful comments on an earlier draft. We thank the advisory board members of the POLICYMIX project as well as all participants of the expert workshop held in Oslo on 7 May 2014. We express our sincere gratitude to two reviewers whose constructive remarks helped to improve the paper.

Author Contributions

Conceived and designed the experiments: MS GMR DNB SB BN. Performed the experiments: MS SB. Analyzed the data: MS GMR DNB SB BN. Contributed reagents/materials/analysis tools: MS GMR DNB SB BN. Contributed to the writing of the manuscript: MS GMR DNB SB BN.

References

  1. 1. Haines-Young R, Potschin M (2010) Proposal for a Common International Classification of Ecosystem Goods and Services (CICES) for integrated environmental and economic accounting. New York, USA: European Environment Agency.
  2. 2. Carpenter SR, Mooney HA, Agard J, Capistrano D, DeFries RS, et al. (2009) Science for managing ecosystem services: Beyond the Millennium Ecosystem Assessment. Proc Natl Acad Sci U S A 106: 1305–1312.
  3. 3. Larigauderie A, Prieur-Richard A-H, Mace GM, Lonsdale M, Mooney HA, et al. (2012) Biodiversity and ecosystem services science for a sustainable planet: the DIVERSITAS vision for 2012–20. Curr Opin Environ Sustain 4: 101–105.
  4. 4. Schröter M, van der Zanden EH, van Oudenhoven APE, Remme RP, Serna-Chavez HM, et al. (2014) Ecosystem services as a contested concept: a synthesis of critique and counter-arguments. Conserv Lett: doi:10.1111/conl.12091.
  5. 5. Mace GM, Norris K, Fitter AH (2012) Biodiversity and ecosystem services: a multilayered relationship. Trends Ecol Evol 27: 19–26.
  6. 6. Faith DP (2012) Common ground for biodiversity and ecosystem services: The “partial protection” challenge [v1; ref status: indexed, http://f1000r.es/QPrmmt]. F1000Research 2012 1.
  7. 7. Reyers B, Polasky S, Tallis H, Mooney HA, Larigauderie A (2012) Finding Common Ground for Biodiversity and Ecosystem Services. Bioscience 62: 503–507.
  8. 8. Chan KMA, Hoshizaki L, Klinkenberg B (2011) Ecosystem services in conservation planning: Targeted benefits vs. co-benefits or costs? PLoS ONE 6: e24378.
  9. 9. Egoh BN, Paracchini ML, Zulian G, Schägner JP, Bidoglio G (2014) Exploring restoration options for habitats, species and ecosystem services in the European Union. J Appl Ecol 51: 899–908.
  10. 10. Egoh B, Rouget M, Reyers B, Knight AT, Cowling RM, et al. (2007) Integrating ecosystem services into conservation assessments: A review. Ecol Econ 63: 714–721.
  11. 11. Chan KMA, Shaw MR, Cameron DR, Underwood EC, Daily GC (2006) Conservation Planning for Ecosystem Services. PLoS Biol 4: e379.
  12. 12. Bennett EM, Peterson GD, Gordon LJ (2009) Understanding relationships among multiple ecosystem services. Ecol Lett 12: 1394–1404.
  13. 13. Faith D (in press) Ecosystem services can promote conservation over conversion and protect local biodiversity, but these local win-wins can be a regional disaster. Aust Zool: doi:10.7882/az.2014.7031.
  14. 14. Certain G, Skarpaas O, Bjerke J-W, Framstad E, Lindholm M, et al. (2011) The Nature Index: A General Framework for Synthesizing Knowledge on the State of Biodiversity. PLoS ONE 6: e18930.
  15. 15. Anderson BJ, Armsworth PR, Eigenbrod F, Thomas CD, Gillings S, et al. (2009) Spatial covariance between biodiversity and other ecosystem service priorities. J Appl Ecol 46: 888–896.
  16. 16. Chhatre A, Agrawal A (2009) Trade-offs and synergies between carbon storage and livelihood benefits from forest commons. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 106: 17667–17670.
  17. 17. Pichancourt J-B, Firn J, Chadès I, Martin TG (2014) Growing biodiverse carbon-rich forests. Global Change Biology 20: 382–393.
  18. 18. Persha L, Agrawal A, Chhatre A (2011) Social and Ecological Synergy: Local Rulemaking, Forest Livelihoods, and Biodiversity Conservation. Science 331: 1606–1608.
  19. 19. Götmark F (2013) Habitat management alternatives for conservation forests in the temperate zone: Review, synthesis, and implications. For Ecol Manag 306: 292–307.
  20. 20. Lindenmayer DB, Franklin JF, Fischer J (2006) General management principles and a checklist of strategies to guide forest biodiversity conservation. Biol Conserv 131: 433–445.
  21. 21. Nordén B, Paltto H, Claesson C, Götmark F (2012) Partial cutting can enhance epiphyte conservation in temperate oak-rich forests. For Ecol Manag 270: 35–44.
  22. 22. Bengtsson J, Angelstam P, Elmqvist T, Emanuelsson U, Folke C, et al. (2003) Reserves, Resilience and Dynamic Landscapes. Ambio 32: 389–396.
  23. 23. Hanski I (2011) Habitat Loss, the Dynamics of Biodiversity, and a Perspective on Conservation. Ambio 40: 248–255.
  24. 24. Daily GC, Ceballos G, Pacheco J, Suzán G, Sánchez-Azofeifa A (2003) Countryside Biogeography of Neotropical Mammals: Conservation Opportunities in Agricultural Landscapes of Costa Rica. Conserv Biol 17: 1814–1826.
  25. 25. Hauer G, Cumming S, Schmiegelow F, Adamowicz W, Weber M, et al. (2010) Tradeoffs between forestry resource and conservation values under alternate policy regimes: A spatial analysis of the western Canadian boreal plains. Ecol Model 221: 2590–2603.
  26. 26. Eigenbrod F, Anderson BJ, Armsworth PR, Heinemeyer A, Jackson SF, et al. (2009) Ecosystem service benefits of contrasting conservation strategies in a human-dominated region. Proc R Soc Biol Sci Ser B 276: 2903–2911.
  27. 27. Nalle DJ, Montgomery CA, Arthur JL, Polasky S, Schumaker NH (2004) Modeling joint production of wildlife and timber. J Environ Econ Manage 48: 997–1017.
  28. 28. Murdoch W, Polasky S, Wilson KA, Possingham HP, Kareiva P, et al. (2007) Maximizing return on investment in conservation. Biol Conserv 139: 375–388.
  29. 29. Barton DN, Blumentrath S, Rusch GM (2013) Policyscape–A Spatially Explicit Evaluation of Voluntary Conservation in a Policy Mix for Biodiversity Conservation in Norway. Soc Nat Resour 26: 1185–1201.
  30. 30. Kålås JA, Viken Å, Henriksen S, Skjelseth S (2010) The 2010 Norwegian Red List for Species. Trondheim: Norwegian Biodiversity Information Centre Norway.
  31. 31. Framstad E, Økland B, Bendiksen E, Bakkestuen V, Blom H, et al. (2002) Evaluering av skogvernet i Norge. NINA fagrapport. Oslo: NINA. 146.
  32. 32. Skjeggedal T, Gundersen V, Harvold KA, Vistad OI (2010) Frivillig vern av skog - evaluering av arbeidsformen (Norwegian: voluntary forest conservation - an evaluation of the approach). Oslo: NIBR/NINA.
  33. 33. Watts ME, Ball IR, Stewart RS, Klein CJ, Wilson K, et al. (2009) Marxan with Zones: Software for optimal conservation based land- and sea-use zoning. Environ Model Softw 24: 1513–1521.
  34. 34. Reyers B, O’Farrell P, Nel J, Wilson K (2012) Expanding the conservation toolbox: conservation planning of multifunctional landscapes. Landsc Ecol 27: 1121–1134.
  35. 35. Egoh BN, Reyers B, Rouget M, Richardson DM (2011) Identifying priority areas for ecosystem service management in South African grasslands. J Environ Manag 92: 1642–1650.
  36. 36. Egoh BN, Reyers B, Carwardine J, Bode M, O’Farrell PJ, et al. (2010) Safeguarding Biodiversity and Ecosystem Services in the Little Karoo, South Africa. Conserv Biol 24: 1021–1030.
  37. 37. Izquierdo AE, Clark ML (2012) Spatial Analysis of Conservation Priorities Based on Ecosystem Services in the Atlantic Forest Region of Misiones, Argentina. Forests 3: 764–786.
  38. 38. Barton DN, Faith DP, Rusch GM, Acevedo H, Paniagua L, et al. (2009) Environmental service payments: Evaluating biodiversity conservation trade-offs and cost-efficiency in the Osa Conservation Area, Costa Rica. J Environ Manag 90: 901–911.
  39. 39. Rusch GM, Barton DN, Bernasconi P, Ramos-Bendaña Z, Pinto R (2013) Best practice guidelines for assessing effectiveness of instruments on biodiversity conservation and ecosystem services provision. POLICYMIX Technical Brief, Issue No 7. Oslo: NINA.
  40. 40. Ring I, May P, Loureiro W, Santos R, Antunes P, et al. (2011) Ecological Fiscal Transfers. In: I Ring and C Schröter-Schlaack, editors. Instrument Mixes for Biodiversity Policies POLICYMIX Report, Issue No 2/2011. Leipzig: Helmholtz Centre for Environmental Research - UFZ. 98–118.
  41. 41. SSB (2012) Statistisk årbok 2012. Oslo, Kongsvinger: SSB.
  42. 42. Meteorological Institute (2012) Monthly normal values. Oslo: Meteorological Institute.
  43. 43. Moen A (1999) National Atlas of Norway: Vegetation. Hønefoss: Norwegian Mapping Authority.
  44. 44. Schröter M, Barton DN, Remme RP, Hein L (2014) Accounting for capacity and flow of ecosystem services: A conceptual model and a case study for Telemark, Norway. Ecol Indic 36: 539–551.
  45. 45. NFLI (2010) Arealressurskart AR5. Ås: National Forest and Landscape Institute (NFLI, Skog og Landskap).
  46. 46. Margules CR, Sarkar S (2007) Systematic conservation planning. Cambridge [etc.]: Cambridge University Press. 270 p.
  47. 47. Framstad E, Blumentrath S, Erikstad L, Bakkestuen V (2012) Naturfaglig evaluering av norske verneområder: Verneområdenes funksjon som økologisk nettverk og toleranse for klimaendringer. NINA rapport 888. Oslo: NINA.
  48. 48. Opdam P, Steingröver E, van Rooij S (2006) Ecological networks: A spatial concept for multi-actor planning of sustainable landscapes. Landsc Urban Plann 75: 322–332.
  49. 49. Directorate for Nature Management (2007) Kartlegging av naturtyper - Verdisetting av biologisk mangfold. DN håndbok 13. Trondheim: Directorate for Nature Management.
  50. 50. Gjerde I, Baumann C (2002) Miljøregistrering i skog - biologisk mangfold. Ås: Norwegian Institute for Forest Research.
  51. 51. Norwegian Environmental Agency (2013) Naturbase. Trondheim: Norwegian Environmental Agency (Miljødirektoratet).
  52. 52. NFLI (2013) Miljøregistrering i skog (Register of important forest habitats), Telemark. Ås: National Forest and Landscape Institute (NFLI, Skog og Landskap).
  53. 53. Makino A, Klein CJ, Beger M, Jupiter SD, Possingham HP (2013) Incorporating Conservation Zone Effectiveness for Protecting Biodiversity in Marine Planning. PLoS ONE 8: e78986.
  54. 54. Faith D (1995) Biodiversity and regional sustainability analysis. Canberra: CSIRO.
  55. 55. Fisher B, Edwards DP, Larsen TH, Ansell FA, Hsu WW, et al. (2011) Cost-effective conservation: calculating biodiversity and logging trade-offs in Southeast Asia. Conserv Lett 4: 443–450.
  56. 56. Søgaard G, Eriksen R, Astrup R, Øyen B-H (2012) Effekter av ulike miljøhensyn på tilgjengelig skogareal og volum i norske skoger. Rapport fra Skog og Landskap 2/2012. Ås: National Forest and Landscape Institute (NFLI, Skog og Landskap).
  57. 57. Wilson KA, Possingham HP, Martin TG, Grantham HS (2010) Key Concepts. In: J. A Ardron, H. P Possingham and C. J Klein, editors. Marxan Good Practices Handbook, Version 2. Victoria, BC, Canada: Pacific Marine Analysis and Research Association. 18–23.
  58. 58. Landis JR, Koch GG (1977) The Measurement of Observer Agreement for Categorical Data. Biometrics 33: 159–174.
  59. 59. Chan KMA, Satterfield T, Goldstein J (2012) Rethinking ecosystem services to better address and navigate cultural values. Ecol Econ 74: 8–18.
  60. 60. Granhus A (2014) Miljøhensyn ved hogst og skogkultur. In: S Tomter and L. S Dalen, editors. Bærekraftig skogbruk i Norge. Ås: Norwegian Forest and Landscape Institute. 90–99.
  61. 61. Joppa LN, Pfaff A (2009) High and Far: Biases in the Location of Protected Areas. PLoS ONE 4: e8273.
  62. 62. Framstad E, Blindheim T, Erikstad L, Thingstad PG, Sloreid SE (2010) Naturfaglig evaluering av norske verneområder. NINA rapport 535. Oslo: NINA.
  63. 63. Venter O, Laurance WF, Iwamura T, Wilson KA, Fuller RA, et al. (2009) Harnessing Carbon Payments to Protect Biodiversity. Science 326: 1368.
  64. 64. Sarkar S, Margules C (2002) Operationalizing biodiversity for conservation planning. J Biosci 27: 299–308.
  65. 65. Carwardine J, Klein CJ, Wilson KA, Pressey RL, Possingham HP (2009) Hitting the target and missing the point: target-based conservation planning in context. Conserv Lett 2: 4–11.
  66. 66. Margules CR, Pressey RL (2000) Systematic conservation planning. Nature 405: 243–253.
  67. 67. Margules CR, Pressey RL, Williams PH (2002) Representing biodiversity: Data and procedures for identifying priority areas for conservation. J Biosci 27: 309–326.
  68. 68. Luck GW, Chan KMA, Klein CJ (2012) Identifying spatial priorities for protecting ecosystem services [v1; ref status: indexed, http://f1000r.es/T0yHOY].F1000Research 2012.
  69. 69. Carwardine J, Wilson KA, Hajkowicz SA, Smith RJ, Klein CJ, et al. (2010) Conservation Planning when Costs Are Uncertain. Conserv Biol 24: 1529–1537.
  70. 70. Chape S, Harrison J, Spalding M, Lysenko I (2005) Measuring the extent and effectiveness of protected areas as an indicator for meeting global biodiversity targets. Philos Trans R Soc Lond B Biol Sci 360: 443–455.
  71. 71. Gaston KJ, Charman K, Jackson SF, Armsworth PR, Bonn A, et al. (2006) The ecological effectiveness of protected areas: The United Kingdom. Biol Conserv 132: 76–87.
  72. 72. Schröter-Schlaack C, Ring I, Koellner T, Santos R, Antunes P, et al. (2014) Intergovernmental fiscal transfers to support local conservation action in Europe. The German Journal of Economic Geography 58: 98–114.
  73. 73. European Commission (2014) Mapping and Assessment of Ecosystems and their Services. Technical Report – 2014-080. Brussels.