Introduction

Agent-based models (ABMs) are used increasingly to simulate rural land-use change (Berger 2001; Valbuena et al. 2010). Compared to the more traditional pattern-mimicking models (Hilferink and Rietveld 1998; Verburg and Overmars 2009) and bio-economic optimization models (van Ittersum et al. 2008), ABMs are better able to represent the diversity of decision-making strategies that underpin land-use change (Bousquet and Le Page 2004; Parker et al. 2008; Polhill et al. 2011). Some ABMs focus on interactions between agents, such as imitation and the spread of knowledge or information (Berger 2001; Macmillan and Huang 2008; Alexander et al. 2013), whilst others focus on the diversity amongst agents in terms of alternative motives and strategies (Karali et al. 2011; Kelley and Evans 2011). Whilst agents in models of urban dynamics are generally mobile (Xie et al. 2007; Brown et al. 2008; Huang et al. 2013), a common feature of ABMs used to simulate rural dynamics is the immutable location of the land-user agent in geographic space, and the limited range of agent roles with a common focus on farmers. In such models, land-use change results when a farmer agent changes the way it uses the land, while the delineation of the agent’s property remains fixed. Few ABMs simulate rural land-use change as the result of land exchange between agents, involving the reallocation of property ownership (Filatova et al. 2011; Schouten et al. 2013). The fixed-property approach seems appropriate when modelling, for example, relatively small changes in management or the adoption of an innovation. We expect, however, that categorical land-use change, such as the conversion from arable farming to livestock farming or from farming to nature conservation, will arise also from land exchange from one agent type to another. This is because a categorical change often requires considerable investment in knowledge and equipment for most land owners (Rounsevell et al. 2003), while it may also lead to undesired social effects such as an alienation from one’s network of peers (Karali et al. 2013a, b), which have been shown to strongly influence the willingness to change (Lokhorst et al. 2010, 2011). This is supported by data from the Dutch Agricultural Economics Institute, which demonstrate that—over a time span of 10 years—farms that undergo a categorical land-use change (e.g., from dairy farming to arable farming) cover about 4 % of the total agricultural area, while parcels that undergo such a change (i.e. from being owned by e.g. a dairy farmer to being owned by an arable farmer) cover about 11 % (Dienst Regelingen; Government Service for Land and Water Management, 2012). If categorical land-use change were brought about only by farmers changing from one land use to the other, the number of parcels that underwent a categorical change should also have been about 4 % (assuming that changing farms have approximately the same number of parcels as other farms). The fact that the change rate of parcels is higher, suggests that for about 7 % of all parcels, land-use change is the result of parcels being sold from one type of farmer to the other. Hence, more than half of the observed land-use change in the Netherlands appears to result from land exchange. Thus, we argue that to effectively simulate categorical land-use change it is necessary to simulate rural land exchange. In this paper we present the development and application of an ABM that simulates land use change as a result of land exchange in rural areas.

The RULEX model (RUral Land EXchange model) simulates land-use change arising from land exchange between different types of land owners in intensively used rural areas. The model was developed for, and tested in, a case study region of about 300 km2 in the east of the Netherlands. Parts of the region have been designated within the Dutch National Ecological Network, and for this reason the provincial government provides financial and organizational support for the acquisition and subsequent conversion of agricultural land to nature. Nature, in this case, refers to the restoration of (semi-) natural habitats (e.g., forest, heathland, and wetland) on what was previously agricultural land. Private estate owners also expand their estates by buying adjacent agricultural land. Hence, the main land claims in this region are from farmers, nature organizations, and private estate owners which are therefore the three types of agents represented in RULEX. The land use types that are distinguished are arable farming, dairying, horticulture, pig-breeding, mixed farming, nature owned by estate owners, and nature owned by nature organizations.

Both the conversion of land from agriculture to nature by means of land exchange between nature organizations, estate owners, and farmers as well as the exchange of land between different agricultural sectors are key processes that lead to land-use change in the region. This raises policy-relevant questions such as: which agricultural sector will grow, which will shrink and where; will farms continue to grow (in land area terms) and is this location-specific; and, why do we observe that the conversion of farmland to nature is slowing down, and will this trend continue into the future? These issues can be encapsulated into a single overarching purpose for developing the RULEX model, which is to understand how land exchange among farmers and between farmers, estate owners, and nature organizations affects rural land-use patterns.

In this paper, we demonstrate how processes of land exchange can be captured and formalized in rules and equations. Including land exchange between different categories of farmers, as well as between farmers and other types of land users, is challenging because the various agents within the land market have different criteria with respect to land value and other financial and legal positions that require different types of data evidence (Geller and Moss 2008). This may also explain why many contemporary land exchange models do not model categorical land-use change since they are limited to rather homogeneous populations of agents (Matthews et al. 2007). We start by describing the case study area and the data that was used in the model development and calibration. Next, we present the general design of the RULEX model, including the calibrated settings, rules and equations. Parameters that could not be obtained from observational data were obtained by calibrating RULEX on land transaction data from 2001 to 2009. We assess the model’s performance by comparing observed and simulated land use, and conclude with a discussion about the model’s strengths and weaknesses and potential applications.

Study area and data

Study area

The RULEX model was calibrated for, and applied to, an area in the East of the Netherlands (Fig. 1), delineated by the stream valley of the “Baakse Beek” (beek is Dutch for brook), and known as the Baakse Beek area. The area is roughly 10 km from north to south and 30 km from east to west. Since the establishment of the EU’s Common Agricultural Policy, the area underwent a transition from mixed farming to specialized farming (mostly intensive dairying) and farm sizes increased considerably in order to benefit from economies of scale. Current-day agriculture is typical of areas in Western Europe with high population pressure leading to intensive farming that is highly efficient from an economic perspective. Despite this, the area is still considered to be a visually attractive, small-scale landscape. Hedgerows, which are conserved by law, and the presence of large numbers of estates and nature reserves contribute to this image. For this reason, tourism forms an important part of the regional economy, and policymakers are concerned with maintaining the traditional character of the landscape. Over the last 20 years, nature restoration has become important in the area. The National Ecological Network (NEN), defined by zoning policies in the 1990s, covers a considerable part of the area (3,804 ha, about 12.7 % of the area, of which 2,769 ha has currently been realized). All agricultural land within this zone is intended to be converted to nature. Land exchange between farmers and nature organizations in achieving this network has been on a voluntary basis, and nature organizations were required legally to pay agricultural market prices for agricultural parcels.

Fig. 1
figure 1

The Baakse Beek area with land use of 2001

The Baakse Beek contained approximately 1,320 land-owning farmers in 2001, which is the initial year of the simulations. About 481 farmers had parcels within the area, but farmsteads that were located outside of the area. These farmers are registered in the agricultural census, which excludes hobby farmers and other farms with an economic size smaller than three NGE (Dutch farm size units). Distributions of the characteristics of the farm(er)s in the Baakse Beek are given in Fig. 2. The area comprised 5,877 (registered) parcels.Footnote 1 A summary of the parcel properties is given in Table 1.

Fig. 2
figure 2

Box-and-whisker plots for farm(er) characteristics for the Baakse Beek area per farming type. Derived from agricultural census data of 2001. From top in clockwise direction: age, physical size (ha) in log scale, and economic size (NGE) in log scale

Table 1 Summary statistics of land parcel characteristics in the Baakse Beek area for the year 2001

Nature organizations that are active in the area are Natuurmonumenten (a private foundation for nature conservation), the State Forestry Service (an independent governmental organization for forestry and nature conservation), Geldersch Landschap & Kasteelen (a private foundation for the conservation of natural and cultural heritage), and 87 private estates. In the Baakse Beek, these organizations owned approximately 176, 733, 50, and 1,788 hectares respectively in 2001.

Data

The following data were available for calibrating model rules, equations, and settings:

  • Agricultural census data, containing economic size, physical size, farmer age and farming type for each farm. We used data from 1999, 2001 and 2009. The data for 2001 were used to set-up the initial model year. Not all records were complete so farms without data were randomly assigned representative properties in line with the available data for other farms. Where farm locations were unavailable, we assume a location outside of the Baakse Beek area and assigned random coordinates from outside of the region (Alam et al. 2014). A unique identifier linked each parcel to its owner, so that farm data could be linked to spatial parcel data (ArcGIS shapefiles), which were available for 2001 and 2009.

  • Records of rural land exchange [Infogroma, (DLG 2012)], including price paid, identity of seller and buyer, and the location of the sold parcels. Using ArcMAP10 the locations of the sold parcels were related to the parcel database and a set of auxiliary data. This allowed us to identify, for each exchange transaction, data on parcel size, soil properties, distance to major roads, villages and nature reserves, being situated inside or outside the areas designated for the NEN, and the distance to this network. These data were used to calibrate parcel evaluation by agents. Furthermore, data on the total number of farmer–farmer land exchange transactions and the total number of farmer–nature land exchange transactions were derived from this database, which were used to fine-tune the model.Footnote 2

  • We used a combination of explorative interviews and conjoint analysis to inform RULEX about parcel evaluation by nature agents and estate owners. Explorative interviews were conducted with seven local representatives at strategic management positions within each of the nature organizations and a lobby organization for estate owners. Additionally, we asked six representatives of two different nature organizations, who were all involved in parcel evaluation before acquisition, to rank fictional parcels from high to low preference. These data were used to calibrate the parcel evaluation by nature agents. All interviews were conducted in 2011. The conjoint analysis was performed in 2013.

  • Finally, additional data came from ancillary sources: price changes in the period 2001–2009 from the Agricultural Economics Institute databases; the rate of farm succession in the Netherlands from the Agricultural Economics Institute reports; and life expectancy tables from reports of the WHO.

We used the following available data to evaluate the performance of the model:

  • A map of observed land-use in 2009. This map was used in three ways: (1) to compare simulated land use trends with observed trends; (2) to compare a cross table of observed land use in 2001 and simulated land use in 2009 with a cross table of observed land use in 2001 and observed land use in 2009 (i.e. conversion-specific change); and (3) by making an overlay of the simulated and observed land use maps, which was classified into (a) observed change simulated correctly as change (i.e., hits), (b) observed change simulated incorrectly as persistence (i.e., misses); (c) observed persistence simulated incorrectly as change (i.e., false alarms); (d) observed persistence simulated correctly as persistence (i.e., correct rejections); and (e) observed change simulated incorrectly as change to the wrong gaining category (i.e., wrong hits) (Brown et al. 2013a). Because of missing data in the agricultural censuses of both years, the area for which both years have complete records covers 83 %. Also, data on the area that belonged to a nature organization or estate owner in 2001 was missing, and had to be inferred from their property in 2009, by subtracting the parcels that belonged to farmers in 2001. Maps of land use in 2001 and 2009 can be found in the online supplement (Fig. s1).

Model description

Here we describe RULEX in a quasi-ODD format (Grimm et al. 2006). Table 2 presents the characteristics of the model and its entities. We present calibrated rules, equations or settings, most of which refer to the online supplement for details. The online supplement contains a pseudo code of this procedure (Fig. s4), as well as a UML Activity diagram (Fig. s5).

Table 2 Description of model characteristics and entities

Model aim

The aim is to understand how land exchange between farmers, estate owners, and nature organizations shape rural land-use patterns.

Agents

Agents in the model represent farmers, nature organizations, and estate owners. Farmer agents have attributes describing their age, the type of farming practiced (viz. arable farmers, dairy farmers etc.), the economic and physical farm size, and whether or not the farm expanded by more than four hectares during the preceding 10-year period. Each farm is linked to a number of parcels in the parcel shapefile. Nature agents represent nature organizations that are active in the land market in the case study region. They are described by the way they evaluate for-sale parcels and their land ownership in the base year. Likewise, estates were modelled as a single entity (comparable to a nature organization), and are described by the way they evaluate for-sale parcels and their land ownership in the base year. These three types of agents differ fundamentally (i.e., they have different motives and aims) as well as structurally (i.e., many individuals versus a few organizations) and hence require a different modelling and calibration approach.

Behaviour of farmer agents

The following behaviours of farmer agents are distinguished: expanding (to benefit from economies of scale) and shrinking (to enhance liquidity in support of the continuation of the farm). The ‘expanders’ try to buy land, while the ‘shrinkers’ try to sell land. Farmer agents that do not participate in the land market may intensify or innovate (i.e. increase economic size while physical size stays constant) or they may do nothing. (Although intensifying/innovating does not lead to land exchange directly, it may affect the farmer agent’s tendency to expand or shrink at a later time step.) The four behaviours were derived from a combination of exploring the empirical census data, from discussion with local stakeholders, and from the logical thought process that land transactions must involve buyers (i.e. expanders) and sellers (i.e. shrinkers). This is a new approach to modelling land use change that focuses on land market transactions. These behaviours are considered to be a function of the farm(er)’s attributes age, farming type, economic size, and physical size.Footnote 3 This function takes the form of a logistic probability equation that allows an estimation of which of the four behaviours each individual farmer is allocated.

The probability of a farmer displaying behaviour type k = 1–4 is:

$$P\left( {behaviour = k} \right) = \frac{{e^{LOGIT(k)} }}{{1 + \mathop \sum \nolimits_{k = 1}^{4} e^{LOGIT(k)} }}$$
(1)

With:

$$\begin{aligned} LOGIT\left( {expander} \right) &= - 2.96 \, {-} \, 0.02 \, Age \, {-} \, 0.01 \, log(Area) + 0.75 \, log(NGE) + 0.61 \hfill \\ &\quad PrevExp + 0.79 \, (Dairy \, * \, log(NGE)) \hfill \\ \end{aligned}$$
(2)
$$ LOGIT(intensifier/innovator) = - 1.40{\mkern 1mu} - {\mkern 1mu} 0.03{\mkern 1mu} Age{\mkern 1mu} - {\mkern 1mu} 0.40{\mkern 1mu} \log (Area) + 0.42{\mkern 1mu} \log (NGE) + 0.80{\mkern 1mu} PrevExp{\mkern 1mu} - {\mkern 1mu} 0.58{\mkern 1mu} (Dairy{\mkern 1mu} *{\mkern 1mu} \log (NGE)) $$
(3)
$$ \begin{aligned} LOGIT\left( {shrinker } \right) &= - 3.47 + 0.02 \, Age + 0.96 \, \log \left( {Area} \right) \, {-} \, 0.43 \, \log (NGE) + 0.23 \hfill \\ &\quad PrevExp \, {-} \, 0.25 \,(Dairy \, * \, \log (NGE)) \hfill \\ \end{aligned} $$
(4)

With Age being the age of the farmer, Area the physical size (ha) of the farm; NGE the economic size of the farm expressed in Dutch size units, which are closely related to a farm’s gross margin; PrevExp a Boolean variable for having expanded by more than 4 ha in the preceding 10 year period, and Dairy a Boolean variable for being a dairy farmer or not. Note that P(behaviour = 4 = stable) follows automatically from 1−the sum of the other probabilities. See the online supplement for details about how the four categories were defined, further specifications of the calibration dataset, and the performance of the regression model.

Behaviour by nature-organization agents and estate-owner agents

We assume that nature organization agents and estate agents are expanders. That is, they only buy land and do not sell land. In reality, nature organizations sell land occasionally, but this usually involves recently purchased agricultural land that is traded with farmers for parcels with a higher potential nature value. The net result of this process is that nature organizations behave only as expanders, aiming to buy those parcels with the highest potential nature value. The degree to which nature organizations expand is determined by a combination of purchasing power and their desire to buy land (see next section).

Parcel evaluation

Shrinking agents (by definition, farmer agents) choose which parcels they want to sell. We assume that they start by selling their least favourable parcels. The parcel appreciation, reflected in the willingness to accept (WTAF) is a function of parcel properties such as agricultural soil suitability and distance to the NEN, but also of the distance between the parcel and the farmstead. Expanding farmer agents use the same parcel evaluation function to estimate their willingness to pay (WTPF) for the parcels in the market. Conversely, nature organization agents have other criteria than farmers when determining their WTP, i.e. the WTPN, which are related to the potential for successful nature restoration. Expanding private estates evaluate parcels solely from the distance to an existing property.

Statistical analysis resulted in the following equations for WTP (see online supplement for details):

For farmers:

$$WTP_{F} = WTA_{F} = (4.16E - 05- 1.89E - 07*SoilSuit- 1.62E - 03*(1/(DistTown + 100)) + 5.26E - 04*(1/(DistNEN + 100)))^{{ - 1}} - 16.85* \left( {DistFarmstead -250} \right)({\sf C}\!\!\!\!\raise.8pt\hbox{=}ha - ^{1} )$$
(5)

where DistFarmstead is the distance between the parcel and the farmstead of the (potential) owner (m), SoilSuit is an indicator for the percentage of the potential yield that can be obtained on the soil in percentage point, DistTown is the distance from the parcel to the nearest town (m), and DistNEN is the distance between the parcel and the NEN (m).

For nature organizations:

$$WTP_{N} = Intercept \, - \, 7.9 \, * \, Distance + 9214 \, * \, Seepage \, - \, 320*GVG \, ({\sf C}\!\!\!\!\raise.8pt\hbox{=} \, ha^{ - 1} )$$
(6)

where Distance is the distance to the nearest existing nature reserve, Seepage is a dummy variable that indicates the presence of exfiltrating groundwater, and GVG is the groundwater level in cm from surface. The intercept is fine-tuned in "Fine tuning and verifying the model" section.

For estate owners:

$$\begin{gathered} WTP_{E} = 35,\!000 \, {\sf C}\!\!\!\!\raise.8pt\hbox{=} \, ha^{ - 1} if \, parcel \, borders \, existing \, property \hfill \\ WTP_{E} = 0 \, {\sf C}\!\!\!\!\raise.8pt\hbox{=} \, ha^{ - 1} for \, any \, other \, parcel \hfill \\ \end{gathered}$$
(7)

Simulations

The RULEX schedule runs as follows: at each time step, each farmer agent is assigned one of the four possible behaviours (expanding, shrinking, intensifying/innovating, or stable). This happens by sampling from the probability distribution described by Eqs. 14. As this is a stochastic process, behaviours of a single agent may vary during the course of a model run. Furthermore, behaviour may change over time, as farmer agents grow older, their specific farming type is affected by price changes (see "Relative competitiveness of farming types" section), and their farms expand or shrink because of previous actions.

Each shrinking agent selects the least favoured parcels to sell. By default, the number of parcels that a farmer agent will sell per year is set to one (this model parameter is explored in "Fine tuning and verifying the model" section). Next, each expanding agent (farmers as well as nature organizations and estate owners) evaluates the parcels that are available for sale. If the WTP of the expanding agent is greater than the WTA of the shrinking agent, the parcel changes owner, provided that the WTP exceeds the minimum market price of 17,000 € ha−1 (see online supplement). When two expanding agents are interested in the same parcel, it is purchased by the agent with the highest WTP. In RULEX, nature organizations can buy as many desirable parcels as their annual budget permits. For individual farmer agents we did not consider budget limits, as information about capital and savings were not available. Instead, the area a farmer agent can buy per year is limited to one-third of the farm size at that moment in time (see online supplement), and we assume that each expanding farmer agent will find the financial means to buy these parcels.

Not all for-sale parcels change owner in a simulation run: those that are not considered attractive enough for any of the expanding agents remain unsold. Likewise, not all expanding agents are likely to succeed in finding a parcel that they want to buy (i.e., that they value higher than the current owner or higher than the minimum market price). The attributes of farmer agents that exchange land are updated accordingly. Physical size is updated by adding or subtracting the area of the bought or sold parcels and economic size is updated by the same ratio as the physical size. The economic size of farmer agents assigned the behaviour intensifying/innovating increases by 0.19 at each time step (see online supplement). Finally, for all farmer agents, age is updated and economic size is updated by applying a farming-type specific annual trend reflecting changes in the market (see next section). Parcels that are sold to a nature organization, estate owner, or to a farmer agent with another farming type change land use.

Relative competitiveness of farming types

The relative competitiveness of one farming type over another is influenced by the changes in agricultural prices that affect gross margins. This is incorporated into RULEX by specifying a type-specific trend in gross margins, which is imposed on the economic size of each individual farmer (the measure of economic farm size, NGE, is roughly proportional to gross margins). As economic farm size affects the behaviour probability (Eqs. 14), these trends in turn, affect the individual farmer agents’ decision-making. By imposing a trend per type (on top of the changes for individual farmers as a result of land exchange), a relative change in the competitiveness of one type compared to another can be simulated.

From empirical data, we arrived at the following annual NGE trends for the period 2001–2009: Dairy −1.0 %; Arable +1.4 %; Horticulture −0.4 %; Pig-breeding 0.7 %; and Mixed 0.2 % (see online supplement for details).

Retirement, succession, and death of farmer agents

As farmer agents become older, many reach the retirement age (65) within a simulation run, and several die. When an agent reaches the retirement age, it either continues ageing or its age is reset to a value normally distributed around 30 with a variance of 16, to simulate farm succession. Whether or not this happens depends on the economic size of the farm at that time step. Farms with a size less than 8.2 NGE are assumed to have no successor while larger farms do have a successor. The threshold was chosen so that 34 % of all current farmers in the area are smaller, which agrees with national succession rates (de Bont and van Everdingen 2010). The correlation between succession and economic size is confirmed by de Bont and van Everdingen (2010) as well as by individual farmers from the area. Thus, succession was derived indirectly from age and economic farm size.

Farmer agents with a farm that is smaller than this threshold by the time they reach the retirement age remain in business. Since the chance of being a shrinking farmer increases with age (Eqs. 14), their dominant behaviour is to sell land. When a farmer agent dies succession is modelled by resetting its age (as above). The death of a farmer agent is determined by the probability of dying from the 2009 WHO Life expectancy table for the Netherlands.

Fine tuning and verifying the model

Fine tuning the model

While RULEX parameters are empirically-derived, some were difficult to estimate because of a lack of data. This concerned the number of parcels a seller agent puts on the market each year (by default set to 1) and the intercept of the WTPN equation (reflecting the combined effect of purchasing power and desire to expand; by default set to 13,000). To assess these parameters, RULEX was run for the period 2001–2009 with varying parameter settings, and the outcomes evaluated using two metrics: (a) the number of transactions for the entire period between farmers (around 500 according to the Infogroma database); (b) the number of transactions for the entire period between farmers and nature organizations (around 18 according to the Infogroma database). We ran each configuration for batches of 10 simulation runs.

Figure 3 shows that the number of transactions between farmers barely responds to the WTPN intercept, while it increases in response to an increase in number of parcels to sell. Setting a value of 2 for number of parcels to sell resulted in around 550 exchange transactions, which is close to the observed number of 500 transactions. The number of transactions between farmers and nature organizations (Fig. 4) responds to both variables. Given that the number of parcels to sell was assigned a value of 2, the best values were achieved with a WTPN intercept of 11,000 (20 transactions; observed = 18).

Fig. 3
figure 3

Response of number of exchange transactions between farmers to the number of parcels to sell and the WTPN intercept; averaged over 10 simulation runs per parameter setting

Fig. 4
figure 4

Response of number of exchange transactions between farmers and nature organizations to the number of parcels to sell and the WTPN intercept; averaged over 10 simulation runs per parameter setting

Historical validation of RULEX (2001–2009)

RULEX was run 100 times, using the above-adjusted settings, in order to evaluate its performance for the period 2001–2009. For each run, we computed the simulated change for each land-use type between 2001 and 2009 in hectares and divided that by the total area (Table 4). Being a stochastic model, RULEX can produce innumerable realizations of change trajectories, reflecting real-world volatility. Similarly, the observed state in 2009 was also one of the innumerable realities that could have resulted from the situation in 2001. Whenever this particular realization (i.e. the observed situation in 2009) fell within the range of simulated realizations, we considered RULEX to have produced results that were consistent with the observational data.

Table 3 shows that RULEX was able to reproduce observed trends in pig-breeding, mixed farming, and the expansion of estates and nature areas. Trends in dairy farming, arable farming, and horticulture, however, were less well reproduced. For dairy farming, the simulations resulted in a small increase whereas a decrease occurred in the observational data. For arable farming, the simulations resulted in a decline while an increase occurred in the observational data. For horticulture, RULEX simulations showed little or no change, but an increase occurred in the observational data.

Table 3 Observed and simulated trends in the main land-use types between 2001–2009

In order to evaluate in more detail which conversions were simulated correctly and which were not, we computed the difference between the observed change (in hectares) and the simulated change (average of 100 simulations, in hectares) for each specific conversion from land use i to land use j. We expressed these differences as fractions of the total area in the base year 2001, which are shown in Table 4. Deviations of more than 1 % of the area are shown in bold.

Table 4 Deviations between simulated and observed conversions as a percentage of the total area of a land use type in 2001 (i)

Table 4 shows that RULEX tends to overestimate the persistence of dairying, pig-breeding, and mixed farming. In practice, land used for dairying in 2001 was more often used for arable or mixed farming in 2009. Land used for mixed farming in 2001 was more often used for arable farming or dairying in 2009. This may be because RULEX only simulates land-use change resulting from land exchange, while observed land-use change may also result from farmers changing from one farming type to another. This is confirmed by a contingency table of all farms that were in the panel database used for the regression analysis in "Behaviour of farmer agents" section. Although the panel data cover another period (1999–2009), these numbers were taken to approximate trends for the study period (2001–2009). Table 5 shows that several farms did indeed change from one farming type to another. Bold-printed conversion numbers in Table 5 correspond to conversions for which Table 4 shows a high deviation (not taking account of farmers who persisted in their farming type).

Table 5 Contingency table of farming type per farm between 1999 and 2009

A more detailed investigation of these farms in the agricultural census revealed the following: farms that were classified as ‘mixed’ in 1999 and as ‘arable’ or ‘dairy’ in 2009 mostly concerned shrinking mixed farms that ceased one of their activities. By doing so, these farms turned from being a mixed farm into an arable or dairy farm. The change from dairy farms to arable farms mostly involved small and shrinking dairy farmers, who sold their cows and their grassland, but retained arable land (most dairy farmers have a few arable fields for fodder production) on which they continued to produce fodder crops. Within the RULEX context, these are shrinking dairy farmers, but in the agricultural census, they were classified as arable farmers. A similar case concerns the land used for dairying in 1999 and for mixed farming in 2009 in which dairy farmers sold cows and grassland, and hence shifted to the category mixed.

Finally, a spatially-explicit model performance assessment was made by overlaying simulated and observed land use maps. Because RULEX outputs vary stochastically, we selected a single model run that we considered to be representative of all model runs. This was done by computing for each parcel the mode of 100 simulations, and then computing for each simulation the deviation from this mode. The simulation with the smallest deviation from the mode was considered to be the most representative simulation (Fig. s6 in the online supplement). The overlay is shown in the online supplement (Fig. s7), and here we show the area classified as Hits (of which some are wrong hits), Misses, False Alarms and Correct Rejections in tabular form (Table 6).

Table 6 Spatially-explicit model performance

Of the area that underwent change, 58 % was simulated to undergo change. When we also require that the target land use category is correctly simulated, this reduces to 26 %. Of the area that remained unchanged, 77 % was also simulated to remain unchanged. In total, correct simulations (whether this concerned change or persistence) occurred over 8,401 ha, or 73 % of the total area. When we also require the target land use category to be correctly simulated, this number becomes 7,677 ha, or 67 %.

Discussion

The results show that RULEX is able to reproduce historic land-use-change trends in the Baakse Beek region, although it tends to overestimate the persistence of dairying, arable farming and pig-breeding. This is partly because RULEX only simulates one mechanism of land-use change, through land exchange, with farmers deciding to change farming type not being simulated. However, because farms in the census data are classified into one farming type category, a small change in management or animal numbers may result in what is perceived to be a land-use change. In particular, the high observed rates of farms changing from dairy to mixed or arable in the census data were often the result of the retirement of farmers leading to sales of cows and some grassland, and the retention of some arable fields to continue growing fodder crops. This was similar for farms changing from mixed to arable or dairy: in most cases this arose from the loss of one of these activities leading to a classification change.

The RULEX model is stochastic since the farmer agent behaviour is sampled from a probability distribution, which is computed for each farm at each time step. Farmer-agent behaviour, and model outcome, are therefore dependent on the fit of the regression models as described in Eqs. 14. The computed McFadden’s R2 for these models was 0.16. Although this can be considered a relatively good fit for these types of data (for comparison, Cotteleer et al. (2008) found an R2 value of 0.04 when distinguishing buyer-farmers (in one year) from non-buying farmers, based on many more independent variables), a large part of the observed farmer behaviour still remains unaccounted for, which adds uncertainty to the model outcomes. This uncertainty increases further because land exchange between farmers depends on the simulated behaviour of two agents and the behaviour in a certain year is partly dependent on the behaviour in previous years. However, the simulated ranges presented in Table 3 suggest that although uncertainties accumulate during a simulation run, the large number of agents within the model and the multiple simulation years leads to a partial cancellation of random errors. This indicates that despite uncertainty at the micro level, simulated land-use change at the macro level is relatively stable.

From a modelling point-of-view, all empirical (agent-based) models are data hungry, often requiring multiple types of qualitative and quantitative data inputs. Gathering and processing social and spatial data for detailed case studies is a labour intensive task, which is why there are only a few descriptive and data-driven ABMs. A prominent feature of the RULEX model is the systematic use of real data (such as maps, census, and semi-structured interviews) for a real landscape and the simulation of a bidding process that occurs in reality rather than for a hypothetical space. Moving away from the more prevalent ‘theoretical’ approaches found in most ABMs of land markets, RULEX explores land exchange processes that are calibrated and validated against real data. This is beneficial as it allows for open cross-validation of the model as well as the exploration of land-use-change futures under various climate and socio-economic change scenarios (e.g. Murray-Rust et al. 2013), making RULEX a potentially powerful policy analysis tool. Before such explorations can be made, a sensitivity analysis of RULEX to a range of model parameters and input variables is needed, which will be the topic of a forthcoming paper. Furthermore, a structural validation could further help to identify the model’s limitations, which would provide a basis for a new cycle of model improvement (Brown et al. 2013a, b). The land exchange mechanism could, for instance, be combined with mechanisms simulating the change of farming type within one agent. This would require that tendencies to change farming type are related to the farm(er) properties as was done for tendencies to sell or buy land. Examples of such exercises can be found in (Guillem et al. 2012; Karali et al. 2013a, b).

The strong empirical grounding of the model had the additional advantage of supporting communication of the model results to stakeholders (farmers, farmer union representatives, provincial policy makers, nature organizations, and estate holders from within the area). During various meetings and workshops, stakeholders indicated that they recognized the simulated processes and thought the model to be a good representation of the case study, albeit a simplification of reality. Farmers indicated that they could identify with the simulated farmer agents. It is also interesting to note that stakeholders found the stochastic nature of RULEX to contribute positively to its plausibility. Farmers recognized in particular the real-world uncertainty associated with decisions about expanding and having to speculate on which parcels will become available for sale in the near future. Policymakers found the stochastic outcomes to be useful in identifying areas within the Baakse Beek that were stable or where the same transactions always occurred (i.e. where intervention was pointless) and which were more uncertain (i.e. where policy measures to steer a particular land use change are likely to be effective).

An important disadvantage of the empirically-grounded approach is the limited flexibility provided by the regression-based decision rules. Although a linear regression with uncorrelated independent variables would allow experimentation with the role of one or more of these variables by adjusting the regression coefficients, this becomes complicated in the case of the non-linear regressions that were used to identify farmer behaviour and farmers’ willingness to pay for parcels. Also, new behaviours or new decision-criteria are difficult to incorporate. Conversely, the part of RULEX that simulates land exchange is independent of the structure and coefficients in Eqs. 17, so theoretically, these equations could be substituted with equations derived from other sources.

Conclusions

In this paper we present an agent-based model that simulates the process of land exchange between different types of land owners as a driver of land-use change. In areas where pressure on land is high and land-use change is to a considerable extent brought about by land exchange, land-exchange mechanisms are important to account for. However, land exchange is not the only process causing land-use change, and a more comprehensive model should account for other land-use change processes as well.

The pertinence of the processes simulated by RULEX was corroborated by stakeholders from within the study area. This refers to both the micro level processes (e.g. farmers’ land selling and buying strategy) and macro level processes (e.g. policy makers recognizing the modelled processes). This suggests that RULEX could be a useful instrument for participatory scenario explorations of, for example, simulations of land-use change in response to drivers such as price changes and changes in soil quality. In addition, RULEX can be used as a laboratory to explore policy options, such as the effect of subsidies on land purchases or zoning policies to achieve nature targets.